(18.218.25.67)
Users online: 13016     
Ijournet
Email id
 

IASSI Quarterly
Year : 2005, Volume : 23, Issue : 3
First page : ( 107) Last page : ( 126)
Print ISSN : 0970-9061.

The role of Co-operatives in Socio-Economic Development in India — A review

Bhole L.M., Professor of Economics

Department of Humanities and Social Sciences, Indian Institute of Technology, Mumbai. Email: bhole@hss.iitb.ac.in

Abstract

The Co-operative from of business organization has been developed and it has existed in many fields of activities across the globe for more than 150 years now. But the performance of Co-operatives all over the world appears to have been below the expected mark. The objective of this Paper is to examine the meaning, evolution, and principles of co-operatives, to review their working, and to discuss their problems abroad and in India. It shows that certain limitations of the principles, motivations and the goals of Co-operatives would come in the way of their development into an Alternative Social Paradigm such as the Co-operative Commonwealth, which really can solve the problems of poverty, inequality, environmental degradation, social conflicts, and so on. In practice, the co-operatives are often riddled with a host of problems such as concentration, State-dependence, top-to-bottom approach, lack of spontaneity, commercialization, power-politics, corruption, etc. The institutionalization of the principle of co-operation has perhaps tended to result into the ideology of cooperativism.

Wherever a man goes, men will pursue him and paw him with their dirty institutions, and, if they can, constrain him to belong to their desperate odd-fellow society.

Henry David Thoreau

Top

Introduction

As a part of his search for an appropriate socio-economic-political system, man has discussed and experimented with the co-operative form of organization in many countries. In India also, the co-operatives have occupied a significant space in the discourse and experimentation on socio-economic reforms or social reconstruction in this century. After 1991, the changing role of co-operatives and the reorientation needed in them in the light of economic reforms has become an important topic of discussion.

There has been great optimism about co-operatives in the minds of co-operative leadership. There is a semantic strength in the world “co-operation” because of which co-operatives evoke a favourable response among the people. While generally people have argued for co-operatives as a solution at the micro and meso levels, some thinkers have presented a vision of the Co-operative Commonwealth (CCW) as a superior alternative to the existing major socio-economic systems.

Despite the efforts of governments and co-operators, the benign impact of co-operatives on the life of society has remained limited in all countries. A great deal of empirical literature on all types of co-operatives in all countries has highlighted that the co-operatives have had only a limited success in terms of even the conventional economic criteria, and that even a beginning has not been made anywhere in the world towards the creation of a Co-operative Social Order, although co-operatives have been in existence for the more than hundred any fifty years by now.

It is in this context that the present Paper seeks to review the principles and role of co-operatives in India. Towards this purpose, the paper seeks to discuss questions such as the following: what are the origins and historical antecedents of co-operatives? What exactly is the meaning, content and purpose of co-operation in co-operatives? What are the major principles and objectives of co-operatives? What is their philosophical and motivational foundation? What is the concept of the Co-operative Commonwealth? What are the conceptual and performance problems of co-operatives abroad and in India.

The paper is divided in three sections. In Section I, we briefly discuss the meaning, evolution, principles of, and the case for co-operatives. Section II discusses certain important conceptual and other problems of co-operatives. The summary and conclusions are stated in Section III.

Top

The Meaning and Nature of Co-operatives

Meaning

To co-operate or co-operation, in dictionary, means to work or act together toward the same end, and to form and operate co-operatives or societies, the members of which jointly own and run business and share profits among themselves. It is in the latter sense that the term cooperation has been mostly used in the context of economic systems; it denotes co-operative institutions, co-operative organizations, and cooperative movements. It is to be noted that co-operation here involves institutionalization and formal arrangements, or the formation of formal business or commercial or financial agencies or enterprises.

The co-operatives in essence are mutualities formed by small economic units to undertake in common certain activities related to their functioning as economic units so as to serve their own economic or material interests by obtaining advantages of modern technology and economies of large scale. The co-operatives, like corporatist associations, are essentially common-interest organizations which are established to serve “categoric material interests”. It is for this reason that they are sometimes described as neo-corporatist organizations. Many people believe that co-operatives are not even mutualities in practice; they very often function as fully independent ordinary economic establishments or entities.

Evolution

The historical roots of modern formal co-operatives as economic agencies can be traced to Medieval European Guilds, mutual self-help associations typical of early industrialization in England, and active social experiments of the Utopian Socialists such as Fourier, Saint Simon, Proudhon, Louis Bank and Robert Owen. Co-operative philosophy and experiments had emerged as a revolt against the ills, failures, exploitation, and evils of capitalism. They originated as answers to hardships and adverse circumstances of the small groups or sections of people. Further, co-operatives appear to have first originated primarily in the fields of trading and commerce. Finally, although in some countries they were set up at the initiative of the people themselves, in many countries they came into being primarily at the initiative of the Governments.

Temporally, the formal co-operativization began in England in the first half of the Nineteenth Century, and it slowly spread to other countries over the next sixty-seventy years. The first consumer cooperative store or shop, The Rochdale Pioneers, was set up at Toad Lane in London in 1844 by industrial workers with a view to fighting their exploitation by small as well as large traders. Subsequently, cooperativization started in the field of credit in Germany in 1852 and in Italy in 1866, in the fields of farming and rural credit in Japan in 1890, and in the field of agriculture in China in 1919. In India, it began in the field of agricultural credit in 1904 at the initiative of Government, which gave it legal backing by passing the Co-operative Society Act, 1904 and the Co-operative Societies Act II, 1912. While the former enabled the setting up of credit societies, the latter covered other areas of activities. By now, the co-operativization has become a widely used form of organization; it exists in almost all countries, under almost all systems, and in almost all fields of activities, albeit with varying degrees of coverage, intensity and success. For example, it now covers the sectors such as production, processing, distribution, marketing, agriculture, industry, service, banking, finance and credit, and housing.

Principles Underlying Co-operatives

From their inception, co-operatives had worked and grown for almost 100 years (1860–1960) without universally agreed upon principles. Although the principles of Rochdale Pioneers, presumably the first cooperative enterprise in the world, have been usually taken as a starting point, the co-operators have often disagreed about the underlying principles, and they have frequently redefined, modified, and restated these principles. This lack of consensus on basic principles for such a long period of time is surely one of the problem areas in the co-operative movement.

In the 1960s the efforts of the International Co-operative Alliance (ICA) resulted in the emergence of the following as the announced principles of co-operation: (i) voluntary association, (ii) democratic management and control, (iii) self-help or mutual help, (iv) open door policy and the secterian, political religious neutrality, (v) equality of members, (vi) one member one vote, (vii) fixed and limited return on investment, (viii) distribution of surplus in dividends in proportion to member's business or capital in the society, (ix) limited liability, and (x) co-operation among co-operatives. It appears that “no profit no loss” is not the basic principle of co-operatives; when it is mentioned as an important principle, profit is referred to as surplus.

Many of these principles are quite different from the principles which formed the basis of Raiffeisen Credit Co-operatives in Germany, and those which were advocated by Robert Owen. Raiffeisen Principles were: (a) each co-operative society should be restricted to a relatively small area of not more than one village, (b) the members of each society must know each other personally, (c) unlimited liability of members, and (d) management on honorary basis. The principles enunciated by Owen were: (i) elimination of private profits, (ii) production for use by consumers in their voluntary associations, (iii) common ownership of means of production, and (iv) the utilization of the wealth for the good of the community. Co-operatives generally do not follow these principles of decentralized communitarian organization.

The Case for Co-operatives

The need for and suitability of co-operatives have been stressed by various official Commissions and Committees, and by different thinkers like Gadgil, Hough, Smith, and others. According to the Royal Commission on Agriculture in India, “if the rural community is to be contented, happy, and prosperous, local Governments must regard the co-operative movement as deserving all the encouragement” (quoted in Victor, 1979, p. 238). Similarly, the Indian Central Banking Inquiry Committee had felt that “the co-operative movement inspire of imperfections and unavoidable setbacks deserves every possible assistance from all quarters because there is no better instrument for raising the level of the agriculturist of this country than the co-operative effort”. Soon after its establishment, the Reserve Bank of India (RBI) opined that “…the very travails of the movement served to reveal that no better alternative was possible. The movement for rural reconstruction can achieve real and durable results only with the co-operative ideal and with a co-operative form and organization” (quoted in Victor, 1979, p. 238).

In a similar vein, Gadgil has argued, “I consider that the ideas, the practices, and the philosophy associated with developments in cooperation in the world are capable of yielding a socio-economic programme which would prove not only of immediate application but also of lasting value to India” (GIPE, 1975, p. 4). Showing restrained optimism, Hough has suggested, “co-operation in India has not worked the miracle its original sponsors hoped for … in the light of the history of the co-operative movement in India, one s attitude towards it can be only one of chastened optimism, yet the evidence is conclusive that its furtherance merits the support of every friend of the people of India” (Hough, 1966, p.371).

Co-operation has been called an economic miracle of the Nineteenth Century. It has been perceived as a superior alternative to capitalism, socialism and communism because it is said to remove the defects of these systems while retaining their advantages. It has also been regarded as a corrective to Statism. On the face of it, the principles of cooperation such as equality of members, one man one vote, and ownership of business by workers or customers or members, have attracted many people towards the co-operatives.

Different thinkers have seen many advantages in co-operative institutions from the point of view of the so called developing countries. It is believed that co-operation can promote development in these countries which is consistent with social justice, particularly in the case of large masses of the rural population. Co-operation enables society to combine small units into sizable groups so as to obtain advantages of large-scale organization and changes in technology. Small men can hold their own and gain in strength and opportunity only if they combine on co-operative lines (Singh, 1969, pp. 122–127).

Given their meta-economic psychological structures, and non-material attitudes and motivations, co-operatives are said to be particularly suitable for the Indian people. According to Hough, out and out materialism can never be acceptable to the masses of India and, therefore, co-operatives offer a way out that does no violence to Indian tradition, and which is well-suited to the genius and national psychology of Indian masses (Hough, 1966, p. 368). It would be apparent to many that such a case for co-operatives is based on the concept of “social dualism” put forth by certain social scientists such as Boeke in development economics.

Unlike Hough Gadgil s case for co-operatives is based on socioeconomic structural conditions in developing countries in general, and India in particular. In agriculture and other primary production activities, in small industry, in transportation and consumer sectors, the co-operative way is regarding eminently suitable because of the existence of overwhelmingly poor and weak economic units, and of a great disparity in strength between the weak and strong, and between the urban and rural sectors there. Co-operative activity is said to be the only way in which such societies can forge ahead peacefully.

Further, it has been argued that in developing countries, many of which are engaged in development planning, the co-operatives can serve to organize various economic units, to learn and understand more of their wishes, aspirations and capacities, and to communicate to them national decisions. All this can go a long way to enhancing the effective implementation of plans. In other words, co-operatives can serve as a very good planning instrument; they can carry out plans with greater scrupulousness, care, and honesty; and, more importantly, they can tackle one of the basic contradictions of a planned system, namely its inexorable march towards over centralization, and its need for public participation.

Some thinkers such as Dey and Gadgil have envisioned co-operatives as a means of great social change, and as an alternative social order. Gadgil particularly has posed it as a better alternative to competitive capitalism, liberal economy, socialism, communism, and even Sarvodaya. This wider vision of co-operatives has been variously referred to as the Co-operative Commonwealth (CCW) or Co-operative Socialist Commonwealth (CSVW) or Co-operative Social Order (CSO) or Co-operative Economy (CE) or Co-operative Form of Society (CFS) or Cooperative Community (CC) (Dey, 1967; and Gadgil, 1975). This principles, structure, organization, and characteristics of CCW as stated by Gadgil and Day can be summarized as follows:

The concept of CCW takes the idea of co-operatives beyond mutuality; it posits that the pristine objective of co-operativization is to create a new social order which would eliminate and not just mitigate the evils or capitalism and other existing systems. The CCW aims at creating a new social order and not just to create a new type of institution within the capitalist or socialist framework. It aspires to build up a structure and foundation of a new transformed society and not to carve out a sheltered area within a capitalist or socialist society. It aims at the ultimate reconstruction of the entire social fabric or communities on cooperative principles. In such a social order, there would be no aggrandizement of the individual and the strong, and no celebration of pecuniary gains; there would be limitations on dividends. The competitive principles and practices would necessarily be given a go by in such a social order. There would be an internalization of the universal cooperative spirit and co-operative attitude among and between the members of the community.

Regarding the motivational foundation, the CCW assumes that men are not guided in their work solely by the hopes of material gain, that people recognize the importance of a group of social obligations; that men can voluntarily accept limitations on their expectations and rewards; and that they can exhibit restraints in behaviour patterns while pursuing economic gains. CCW takes a moral view of economic activity; it regards moral values as being a non-separable part of economic life; and it explicitly incorporates ethical values such as social justice, social obligation, and concern for others into the socio-economic structure. CCW is explicitly a moral economy.

In CCW, production and other economic activities would be organized, as far as possible, in small, local, primary, independent cooperative units or enterprises; CCW insists on the centrality, primacy and the paramount importance of such units. There would be an emphasis on the dispersal and decentralization of economic activity, and on a great diffusion of ownership of resources and power. While private property would not be entirely abolished, its share in national wealth would be as low as possible. CCW posits anti-monopolistic stance, equality of distributive shares, and absence of wide differentials in remuneration for individual effort. As the same time, it is said that CCW would not emphasize public ownership of means of production. However, it would favour that the control of large-scale oligopolistic undertakings is placed in the hands of the public authority. There would be a creation of an egalitarian society, not as a precondition but as something which would be achieved through the practice of co-operation. In other world, CCW would be an economic democracy in which privileges of any kind would not be countenanced. It accepts the existence of possible conflicts between different interest groups and regions, but it would make arrangements for a peaceful settlement of these conflicts.

How would the CCW operate? How would it be guided or regulated? It has been argued that the co-operative economy would neither be an autonomous nor a free market economy; its emphasis would be on organizing all activities for mutual advantage at various levels, right from the primary level to the highest possible level. Hence, such an order would essentially be a planned order, not a centralized but decentralized planned order in which decentralized decision-making is significantly allied to the planning process. In administrative and political spheres, it would promote and reinforce federalism or federal political ideology.

The State would have a great role to play in CCW. It is visualized that the State would be an important instrument for instilling cooperatives values in those spheres in which actual co-operative organizations may not be established. The complete CCW can come into being and can function only through such help from the State. CCW, while being voluntary, would not keep away from the State; it would accept the State aid “to the extent it is required and is beneficial, and for the necessary period”. The State intervention would be welcomed wherever and whenever security and welfare could not be achieved through mutual help. CCW is said to be radically different from the older isolated self-sufficient co-operative communities. The “State-sponsored co-operatives” would not be regarded as a contradiction in terms under CCW.

Top

Problems of Co-operatives

After having discussed the nature of and the case for co-operatives, we highlight hereafter certain important problems or points of weaknesses and limitations of co-operatives which have been discussed by various authors.

  1. Many of the principles of co-operatives enunciated by the ICA make them only marginally different from the partnership firms and joint-stock companies in respect of organization, objectives, and attitudes. They relate primarily to organization and management and they are open to diverse interpretations and reservations. For example, the principle of open membership tends to make the size of co-operatives unwieldy, and if this principle is discarded, they become closed-ended organizations or the preserves of vested interests. The basis of sharing the gains among the members of co-operatives does not come up to the ideals such as “to everyone according to need, and from everybody according to capacity”, and trusteeship. The principle of mutuality is compromised because the governments and international development and financial agencies often finance co-operatives and prescribe certain rules and regulations. Similarly, the co-operatives now cover a number of establishments, which are non-mutualities.

    The principle of voluntariness is also underminded because quite often the co-operatives are sponsored or promoted by the state, and incentives, inducements, concessions and privileges are offered to increase their membership. Generally, the most disadvantaged and the poorest have not been able to take to co-operatives spontaneously and successfully. The co-operative movement has often suffered from the lack of real popular or mass base; it is neither fully understood nor widely supported at the village level. The story of co-operatives has often been a “top-down” and not “bottom-up” story. The co-operatives in a number of cases have not succeeded in enlisting the enthusiasm and active participation of their members. They have rarely emerged in response to the felt needs of the members, and through their initiative (Baviskar, 1980, p. 3). The main body of principles and practices of co-operatives have been developed as per the situations, conditions and requirements of Western countries. In India, consumer cooperatives appear to have been imported from England, producer co-operatives from France, and credit co-operatives from Germany.

  2. The admirable and desirable value such as co-operation tends to lose its potential when it is formalized into an institution or organization. The co-operative organization may not do good in the way people s latent co-operative capacity or propensity can because of the bureaucratic formalism which characterizes the former. Regulations, managerial hierarchies, committee rule, paper work, and so on make it difficult for all the people to participate, and participate equally, in the affairs of co-operative institutions. The co-operatives generally tend to be either “member-controlled” or “techno-bureaucratic-controlled” organizations which many times suffer from the “institutionalization of suspicion”.

    The institution, power, and money are mostly inseparable. In institutionalized co-operation, money, authority, power, usually become more important guiding forces, and pragmatism becomes as overriding consideration. The institutions have their own economics, politics, and power dynamics; they may create appetite for power and wealth, and scope for misuse or abuse of power. Therefore, the wise have advised, as far as possible, the freedom from money (Kanchanmukti) and freedom from institutions (Sansthamukti) as being necessary for social development.

    The real co-operative relationship among people can be achieved mostly in informal arrangements when co-operation involves altruism, compassion, service and sacrifice; when there is “working for others” than “working with others” to fight or deal with the “enemy” or “others”. The formal co-operatives, which are specific in character, purpose, and activity operate in the framework of individualism, market, and State. The growth and spread of formal co-operatives in practice has generally given rise to co-operativism or co-operative capitalism. The cooperatives have generally evolved into powerful and dominant economic-political institutions in which the masses have a place or participation essentially as instruments. It has been rightly pointed out that the formal co-operatives have grown alongside a decline in the sense of social and religious kinship and communitarian ethos (Namjoshi, 1977, p. 21.).

    The very move to institutionalize any principle generally stems from such motives as would vitiate that principle. The consumers, borrowers, farmers, and others mostly form cooperatives to maximize their group self-interest, which means a shift from the “ethos of co-operation among all” to “a cooperative of some”. The institutionalized co-operation may conflict with other important values such as “small is beautiful” and “self-consumptive production” also. The dangers of institutionalization of co-operation can be seen in the many cases of continuous, often violent, feuds among the members of various types of co-operatives, the frequent member-requested intervention by the government “administrators” in the running of co-operative societies, the phenomenal growth of co-operative courts and the cases in them, and the greed, corruption, and the pursuit of power in many co-operatives.

  3. Co-operatives implicitly accept the philosophy that there is an inevitable conflict, antagonism, struggle, war between the interests of different groups, sections, communities, classes, and other similar social divisions. They try to provide an institutional mechanism to organize people of given interests to protect, safeguard, promote, and fortify their self-interests. They hardly promote the interests and strivings of the society as a whole. The vision of co-operation between all interest groups based on the motivation of altruism, service is generally absent in institutional co-operation. A recent study of the co-operative movements around the world has highlighted the absence of inter-co-operative co-operation and collaboration. Despite the obvious advantages, the co-operation among co-operatives is uncommon on either the national or international scene. The “consumer-production dichotomy” underlines the working of cooperatives (Plunkett Foundation, 1995, pp. 1–2).

  4. The co-operatives can play only a limited role in a radical social transformation because they are essentially business and commercial enterprises. As Mark and Walras have pointed out, they came into being to enable certain specific interests to accumulate capital, to become entrepreneurs, to secure an extension of State activities and so on (see Namjoshi, 1977, pp. 28–29). Their guiding value system comprises efficiency, productivity, surplus, dividends, and similar other values. They do not come into being to address broader or wider social, economic and political issues. Liek the corporates, they also suffer from the problems of agency costs, moral hazard, adverse selection, and x-inefficiency. Even if they are associations, they are “common interest-group associations” and not “social entity associations”. Consequently, they tend to safeguard the interest of their members even at the cost of wider social interest, and their mutuality often does not contribute to community interests.

    As business enterprises, the motivational foundation of cooperatives is the maximization of economic or pecuniary selfinterest. The motivation of co-operatives namely, “mutual aid for individual gain” is distinctly different from the ideas of socialization and communitarian living. The widely accepted definitions of co-operatives reflect this quite well. It is said that “co-operative is self-help made effective by organization”, or “co-operative is a form of organization wherein persons voluntarily associate together…. for the promotion of economic interests of themselves”, or “in its broadest sense, a co-operative is a voluntary association in a joint undertaking for mutual benefit-admittedly a lower ideal than a joint effort directed at the common good” (See Hough, 1966, p.41).

    The incentive system in co-operatives, as under private capitalism, is one of “positive economic gains” and “negative sanctions”. The co-operatives also foster acquisitive, accumulating and achieving mind-set. The internal and external performance appraisal of co-operatives (by management, State, committees, academics) is done in terms of narrow economic indicators such as volume of output and sales, efficiency, productivity, diversification, successful competition, foreign exchange, wages, prices, surplus or dividend, and size. Generally, the co-operatives neither came into being, nor are they being run, nor are they being assessed in terms of vital broader issues such as the structure of production, distribution of goods, health of people, social welfare, ethics and morals, environmental and ecological impact, and so on. It has been put rather harshly that co-operatives are a capitalist wolf clad in an egalitarian rhetoric (Robertson, 1984). Robert Owen had termed Rochdale Pioneer s Consumer Society as an experiment in jointstockkeeping rather than as a co-operative (see Victor, 1979, pp. 70–74).

  5. Co-operatives have frequently failed in offering right solutions to the problems of what to produce?, how to produce?, and for whom to produce? In many cases, they have not been producing, on priority basis, those goods and services which meet the basic or primary needs of the poor masses. They have, often enthusiastically and without any qualms, entered into the production of luxury and harmful goods. The have been often instrumental in promoting the structural retrogression in various economies. They have contributed to the creation of mass consumption societies, particularly in respect of products of display, entertainment, and ostentation.

    Similarly, the co-operatives have generally failed to promote appropriate technology, indigenous technology, and indigenous knowledge systems. They appear to vie with corporates in using large-scale, high, sophisticated, capital-intensive, energyintensive, labour-saving technology. Further, the principles of social justice or distributional justice are not the core principles of co-operatives. They have been found to be a rather weak means for countering poverty, exploitation, and inequality. It appears that within the co-operatives also, perhaps only the voting power is equal, while other things such as distribution of surplus, control, participation are unequal.

  6. Sri Aurobindo once said that many problems faced by man inter alia are due to his creation of organizations, structures, institutions which are so large-sized and complex that his limited intellect cannot manage them well. Like certain State and private corporate sector enterprises, many co-operative enterprises also have become huge, multi-purpose, centralized, and bureaucratized organizations, which operate beyond a village in the national and international arena. In their quest for tapping the economies of scale, co-operatives have exhibited a tendency towards bigness and centralization. They have often been instrumental in reducing the number of individual proprietorship form of business organizations.

    In certain fields they have tended to become either oligopolies or monopolies. In India, for example, they have entered into monopoly procurement, trading, and marketing of commodities such as cotton, milk, onions, and jowar. The organizations such as Maharashtra State Co-operative Marketing Society, Maharashta State Co-operative Marketing Federation, National Federation of Co-operative Sugar Factories, and Federation of State Co-operative Banks are huge organizations with Statewide and Nation-wide reach. They are characterized by the horizontal and vertical integration in which the responsibility, decision-making power, and overall management and control are centralized at the apex level.

    The federal structure of co-operatives or federalism in the co-operative sector has not helped to solve the problems of centralization. The co-operative federations have tended to reduce the democratic content and mutuality in the co-operative movement. The upper tiers or federations do not deal with the individual members of the co-operative societies. The existence of the district-level, State-level, and National level co-operatives and their federations has made co-operatives huge, complex, and impersonal superstructures in which there is little personal knowledge, acquaintance, and relationship among the members. It has been found that in USA and Denmark, the main bulk of co-operative work and the responsibility to take decisions have been transferred from the small local units to the larger federal organizations (Victor, 1979, pp. 74–77). In UK, the functioning of co-operatives as private microcosms of ancillaries to the national democracy has become much muted and weakened. The participation of members in meetings has declined, and their apathy has increased in large co-operative societies. In India also, the democratic control is nominal, it lacks vigour and vitality, and there is little real internal autonomy in the functioning of large-sized co-operatives and co-operative federations (Krishnaswami, 1976, pp. 4–6 and p. 235).

  7. It has been pointed out by some that co-operatives the world over have entered into the politics of distribution, fixing prices, and location of factories (Curtis, 1991, p. 62). A study of marketing co-operatives in Tamil Nadu in India has revealed that the influence of the Central and State government in these institutions has increased over the years. These co-operatives have been unable to eradicate unnecessary middlemen, and yet, they have been perpetuated and expanded with government subsidies year after year (Hariss, 1984, p. 220).

    There is evidence to show that co-operative farming does not result in the development of agriculture in general and small farmers in particular. Where the decision to joint farm cooperatives or not lies with the peasants, they shy away for such co-operatives. If the co-operative farms do come into existence, they disintegrate soon enough. If they do continue to function, their productive performance hardly ever matches that of wellmanaged private farms. The causes for these are embedded in the structural features of agricultural co-operatives (Deshpande, 1977, pp.1–5). A study of forest co-operatives in Gujarat has shown that (a) they have undertaken ruthless destruction of the forests; (b) they do not involve the poorest sections of society in any significant way; (c) they frequently pay their labourers below the legal minimum wage, and (d) they have not done any better than commercial organizations such as Forest Corporations, and contractors or middlemen in respect of social welfare (Dogra, 1986, p. 1884).

    The evidence on co-operative sugar factories is equally revealing. In Maharashtra, they account for hardly three percent of the total cultivable area, but they use more than seventy five percent of water. They have strongly opposed the Government policy for equitable distribution of water even during drought conditions. They indulge in cutthroat competition and maintain private “armies” which they use to compel farmers to deliver cane to themselves. They compulsorily deduct a part of the final price of cane paid to the grower-shareholders and credit this money as contributions to the public and private trusts which are controlled by their leaders. The “Sugar barons” or “Sugar Samrats” occupy top positions in co-operatives year after year (for, say 25 years), and even pass on their positions to their children and relatives. They have set up distilleries in a big way, and they are making huge profits by selling many varieties of liquor. The co-operative sugar factories have brought about a change in the structure and style of politics in their areas of operation, and a symbiotic relationship between co-operatives and politics has grown in which the two sustain each other. They have taken politics to the villages in the worst forms, and have condemned the rural society to permanent factional feuds, rivalries, and political competition. The enourmous political power wielded by co-operative “leaders” coupled with the interlocking positions occupied by them in the other authority-structures has increased inequalities in the distribution of power. The elections in these co-operatives are fought viciously by using any and every means. The sugar cooperatives lack internal democracy; they are nowhere near the idea of the co-operative commonwealth (Baviskar, 1980, p. 1 and pp. 70–186).

  8. Co-operatives, like public and private sector enterprises, are dominated by leaders, bureaucrats, and experts. They are managed by salaried staff, which is not accountable to members who, in fact, become subordinate and subservient to this staff. The bureaucrats in co-operatives also have great power, high status, sense of superiority, attitude of superciliousness, and contempt for the masses. They are appointed by an outside authority and they cannot be removed by the members.

    The “management” of co-operatives has become more important than member initiative and mutual help and trust. The co-operatives are not free from the culture of secretaries, technicians, managers, consultants, advisers, and so on. They have come to depend on non-local leadership, the formal training of which has become a huge activity. Co-operatives have contributed to the deskilling of indigenous societies; they set out to organize small, poor, local people but have ended up by destroying the local people s roots, skills, and value system.

  9. Co-operatives have not been in a position to mitigate the problems of the “market system”. As said earlier also, in their efforts to protect certain economic interests and to act as the “countervailing power” against the private sector monopolies and oligopolies, often they themselves have become oligopolies and monopolies. There is really little to choose between the private, State, and co-operative imperfect markets. The price levels arrived at by co-operatives tend to be quite similar to those arrived at under the private competitive capitalism. Cooperatives do not reject, either in principle or in practice, the philosophy and psychology of competition, incentives under competition, and competitive pricing. They can hardly ever develop into “an alternative” to the Market System.

    At the same time, they can hardly contribute to the minimization (withering away) of the role and power of the State. As it has been pointed out, it is only when the widespread State machinery has reconstructed the village and villager that the voluntary co-operative efforts by the people themselves can make further headway with adequate grants and subventions from the government (Hough, 1966, p. 317). The co-operatives have become State-sponsored and State-dependent institutions everywhere. The high level of State intervention and State interference is regarded as essential to remedy various problems of co-operatives.

    The State generally does not regard co-operatives as an independent alternative system of self-help and grass-root democracy. Although co-operatives sound non-contentious, fair, democratic, and participative with rules prescribed by the authorities, burdened with government funds, and supervised by government personnel, they are at best some kind of a branch of national administration (Curtis, 1991., p. 52). There has been a two-way relationship between the State and co-operatives. While the co-operatives are often a creation of official action, they have, in turn, generally acted as the instruments or agents for implementing the official policies. Experience shows that the co-operatives do not stand apart from the State; they work closely with the State.

    The evidence from the countries such as France, Mexico, Italy, Turkey, Japan, and India shows that co-operatives abet and consolidate the State. As Gadgil has highlighted, “co-operation in these countries was … a formal apparatus … for giving effect to State policy. Ordinarily, the initiation of the cooperative effort was undertaken as a part of an official programme” (GIPE, 1975, p. 23). In China, both before and after 1950, the partnership between the government and the co-operatives has been such that co-operative societies are so only in name. The Agricultural Producers Co-operatives are really agricultural communes whose annual plans are approved, whose priorities are determined, and who are financed by the State and Communist Party (Victor, 1979, pp. 83–85).

    In India, the All-India Rural Credit Survey Committee had categorically recommended that if co-operatives are to succeed, the State should help them as a partner. The Third Five-Year plan also had stated that in a planned economy, co-operatives should progressively become the basis of organization in certain branches of economic life (Hough, 1966, pp. 386–388). The cooperatives in India are said to have been mostly set up by the Registrars and the resolutions and laws of the State; they have been administered, almost wholly, by the huge posse of Registrars, Assistant Registrars, and Auditors who inspect, supervise, monitor, control, and direct all types of co-operatives. The co-operative movement in India has come to be known as “Co-operative Registrars movement”. What has existed in India all the time is not so much “the movement through community co-operation” but “the State co-operative policy”. The cooperatives in India are said to be “public sector co-operatives” (Hough, 1966, p. xii).

  10. Although the vision of CCW is very attractive, so far it remains quite vague. As it has been pointed out, the consensual conception of CCW has not been spelt out by anyone so far (Namjoshi, 1977, pp 41–44). The CCW is expected to operate as a part of the planned economy. In CCW the State would provide not only legalistic structures and regulatory systems but it would also perform many more functions. Given the role assigned to modern democracy, federalism, welfare functions, planning, and public utilities, CCW cannot be said to be much different from the Mixed Economy or Welfare State.

Top

Summary and Conclusions

The co-operatives have been in existence in the World for more than 150 years now. The empirical evidence from all the countries including India on all types of co-operatives shows that they have succeeded in achieving most of their objectives only to a limited extent, and they have not been able to develop into an alternative social order such as the cooperative commonwealth. In the 1950s, it was said that the “co-operation has failed but it must succeed”. However, the limitations of the basic principles, motivations, and goals of institutionalized co-operation imply that even if the co-operatives succeed, it would be so in achieving rather limited and sectional objectives. In future also, the co-operatives can hardly develop into an Alternative Social Paadigm, which can effectively solve today s urgent problems such as poverty, inequality, environmental degradation, and conflicts of a diverse nature. Some of the problems of typical co-operatives today are: the multi-purpose vertical federal structure, concentration and centralization, State-sponsorship and Statedependence, top-to-bottom approach, outside leadership, lack of spontaneity, failure to serve the neediest social strata, commercialization, agent-status, consumerism, power politics, and corruption. The institutionalization of the principle of co-operation has perhaps tended to result in the emergence of an ideology of co-operativism.

Top

References

ApthropeR.Rural Co-operatives and Planned Change in Africa: An Analytical Overview, UNRSID, Geneva, 1972.

TopBack

ArgyleM.Co-operation: The Basis of Sociability, Roultedge, London, 1991.

TopBack

Altwood, BaviskarB.S. (eds), Who Shares? Co-operatives and Rural Development, Oxford University Press, New Delhi, 1988.

TopBack

BaviskarB.S.The Politics of Development: Sugar Co-operatives in Rural Maharastra, Oxford University Press, Delhi, 1980.

TopBack

BholeL.M.“Is Corporatism an Alternative Social Order”, Man and Development, September, 1993.

TopBack

ChaudhuryK.M.An Assessment of Co-operative Farming Societies in Gujarat and Rajasthan, Sadar Patel Univeristy, Vallabh Vidyanagar, 1972.

TopBack

ChinchankarP.Y., NamjoshiM.V. (eds) Co-operatives and Dynamics of Change, Somaiya, Bombay, 1977.

TopBack

CombsAllan (ed.), Co-operatives: Beyond the Age of Competition, Gordan and Breach, Tokyo, 1992.

TopBack

Curtis, DonaldBeyond Government: Organization for Common Benefit, Macmillan, London, 1991.

TopBack

DalayaC.K., SubnisR.S.Co-operation in Maharashta, Centre for the Study of Social Change, Bombay, 1963.

TopBack

DashT.R.Co-operatives and Economic Development, Vedam Books, New Delhi, 1998.

TopBack

DeshpandeS.H.Some Problems of Co-operative Farming, Himalaya, Bombay, 1977.

TopBack

DeyS.K.Sahakari Samaj: The Co-operative Commonwealth, Asia, Bombay, 1967.

TopBack

DigbyM.Co-operative Land Use: A Challenge to Traditional Co-operation, Basil Blackwell, Oxford, 1963.

TopBack

DograBharatGujarat: Not A Model To Emulate, Economic and Political Weekly, October 25, 1986.

TopBack

GandhiM.K.Co-operative Farming, Navjivan, Ahmedabad, 1959.

TopBack

GeorgeShantiMatter of People: Co-operative Dairying in India and Zimbabwe, Oxford University Press, New Delhi, 1994.

TopBack

Gokhale Institute of Politics and Economics (GIPE), Writtings and Speeches of Prof. D.R. Gadgil on Co-operation, Orient Longman, Bombay, 1975.

TopBack

HarissBarbaraState and Market, Concept, New Delhi, 1984.

TopBack

HoughE.M.The Co-operative Movement in India, Oxford University Press, Calcutta1966.

TopBack

InamdarN.R.Government and Co-operative Sugar Factories, Popular, Bombay, 1965.

TopBack

International Co-operative Alliance, The Role of Co-operation in Social and Economic Development, Asia, Bombay, 1966.

TopBack

KrishnaswamiO.R.Co-operative Democracy in Action, Somaiya, Bombay, 1976.

TopBack

KrishnaswamiO.R.Fundamentals of Co-operation, S. Chand, New Delhi, 1978.

TopBack

KulkarniK.R.Theory and Practice of Co-operatives in India and Abroad, Co-operators' Book Depot, Bombay, 1958.

TopBack

LaxminarayanH, KanungoK.Glimpses of Co-operative Farming in India, Asia, Bombay, 1967.

TopBack

MascarenhasR.C.A Startegy of Rural Development: Dairy Co-operatives in India, SAGE, New Delhi, 1988.

TopBack

NamjoshiM.V.Co-operation and Welfare, in ChinchankarP.Y., NamjoshiM.V. (eds) Co-operatives and Dynamics of Change, Somaiya, Bombay, 1977.

TopBack

Plunkett Foundation, The World of Co-operative Enterprise, Plunkett Foundation, Oxford, 1995.

TopBack

RajgopalA.Tamil Nadu Co-operative Movement in Peril, Economic and Political Weekly, October, 29, 1988.

TopBack

RajagopalanS.Co-operation in Foreign Countries, V.S.N. Chari & Co., Madras, 1955.

TopBack

RajKrishna Others, Co-operative Faming: Some Critical Reflections, Indian Cooperative Union, New Delhi, 1956.

TopBack

Rath, NilkanthaD.R. Gadgil on Co-operative Commonwealth, Economic and Political Weekly, April 6, 2002.

TopBack

RobertsonE.F.People and the State, Cambridge Unviersity Press, Cambridge, 1984.

TopBack

Roy, DurgadasAgricultural Co-operatives and Economic Development, Nalanda Publications, Calcutta, 1989.

TopBack

RudraAshokIndian Agricultural Economics, Myths and Realities, Allied, New Delhi, 1982.

TopBack

SaxenaK.K.Evolution of Co-operative Thought, Somaiya, Bombay.

TopBack

SchillarOtto, M.Co-operative Farming and Individual Farming on Co-operative Lines, Indian Co-operative Union, New Delhi, 1957.

TopBack

SchillerOtto, M.Co-operation and Integration of Agricultural Production, Asia, Bombay, 1969.

TopBack

SelvarajuR.Co-operatives in New Millenium, Vikas, New Delhi, 1999.

TopBack

ShahD.R.Co-operatives: An Instrument of Social Change, Rawat, Jaipur, 1992.

TopBack

SinghTarlokTowards An Integrated Society, Orient Longmans, New Delhi, 1969.

TopBack

SinhaB.K.Indian Co-operation, Bookhire, New Delhi, 1970.

TopBack

SureshK.A., JosephM.Co-operatives and Rural Development in India, Ashish, New Delhi.

TopBack

Thorner, DanielAgricultural Co-operatives in India: A Field Report, Asia, Bombay, 1964.

TopBack

TripathyS.N.Co-operatives: Its Growth and New Dimensions, Discovery Publishing House, New Delhi, 2000.

TopBack

TyagiR.B.Recent Trends in the Co-operative Movement in India, Asia, Bombay, 1968.

TopBack

UN Research Institute for Social Development, Rural Co-operatives as Agents of Social Change: A Research Report and a Debate, Geneva, 1975.

TopBack

VictorM.A.Co-operation, Open Education Corporation, Madras, 1979.

TopBack

WorselyP.Two Blades of Grass: Rural Co-operatives in Agricultural Modernization, Manchester University Press, Manchester, 1971.

TopBack

 
║ Site map ║ Privacy Policy ║ Copyright ║ Terms & Conditions ║ Page Rank Tool
751,245,211 visitor(s) since 30th May, 2005.
All rights reserved. Site designed and maintained by DIVA ENTERPRISES PVT. LTD..
Note: Please use Internet Explorer (6.0 or above). Some functionalities may not work in other browsers.